On May 7, 2002, the Central Bank of Iceland published the May issue of Peningamál (Monetary Bulletin), including the Bank's quarterly inflation forecast. Appreciation of the króna and a cooling economy is expected to lead to rapidly declining inflation this year. According to the forecast, inflation over the next four quarters will be 3.2%, but 2.8% in the course of 2002. The outlook for 2003 has improved markedly since the Bank's latest forecast. Inflation two years ahead is forecast to be 2.3%, given an unchanged monetary stance. The Central Bank's inflation target is 2.5%.
The English translation of Peningamál, Monetary Bulletin, will appear on the Bank's website, each chapter as soon as it becomes available. Attached is a preliminary English translation of the Bulletin's introductory chapter.
Consumer price inflation in Iceland 1999 to 2004
Annual percentage change
Year-on-year
In the course of the year
1999
3.4
5.8
2000
5.0
3.5
2001
6.7
9.4
2002
5.3
2.8
2003
3.2
2.3
Quarterly forecast (four and eight quarters ahead)
Annualised quarterly change
Percentage change from year ago
2002: Q-1
4.2
8.7
2003 Q-1
3.7
3.2
2004 Q-1
2.6
2.3
Figures for 2002 and 2003 in the first half of this table and 2003 and 2004 in the second half indicates forecast.
Inflation forecast, May 2002 (figure)
Preliminary translation of the introductory chapter in the May 2002 issue of the Central Bank of Iceland's Monetary Bulletin:
Inflation outlook and contraction create scope for cutting interest rates
Inflation has been on the decrease in recent months. The exchange rate of the
króna has appreciated in step with the rapidly decreasing current account
deficit. At the same time, domestic demand has continued to contract and the
outlook is for some contraction in GDP this year, after a long period of robust
growth. The overheating that prevailed in the goods and labour markets has
rapidly dwindled and is likely to be turning into slack at the present time.
These conditions are favourable with regard to reducing inflation but represent
a difficult adjustment for businesses and households which could affect the
financial system.
Inflation during the first quarter of the year was
slightly lower than the Central Bank had forecast in its last Monetary Bulletin,
which is explained by special government measures and the effects of changes
made in the CPI base. Excluding these factors, the forecast would have been too
low. Nonetheless, underlying inflation has declined sharply, as predicted last
time by the Bank. After adjustment for the above factors, underlying inflation
can be estimated to have been 4% during the past three months, which is a much
lower rate than in the second half of last year. Coupled with the higher
exchange rate of the króna, this development makes it highly unlikely that the
CPI will exceed this May's targets set by the partners on the labour market
which would trigger a review of wage agreements.
There are an
increasing number of signs that the overheated economy has been rapidly cooling
down and that some slack may even have emerged already. While the positive
output gap previously played a significant part in escalating inflation, slack
will help to contain it. In this context, developments in the labour market are
crucial. There are indications that wage drift in the general labour market has
virtually come to a halt and could have turned negative in some sectors.
Cyclically adjusted unemployment is also increasing by the month, people are
working fewer hours and the participation rate is falling.
In its last
inflation forecast, the Bank did not expect its inflation target to be met in
2003, given the assumptions. Together with a high inflation rate during the
months before the forecast was made, this reduced the scope for the Bank to
counteract the contraction by cutting interest rates. However, it was pointed
out that the assumptions could change relatively quickly in this respect,
especially if the exchange rate of the króna strengthened further and/or the
positive output gap closed more quickly than had been assumed. This turned out
to be the case. The inflation forecast presented here is based on an exchange
rate just over 5% higher than the previous forecast, and assumed wage drift has
been lowered. The outcome is that the Bank's target of a 2½% rate of inflation
will be attained during the closing months of 2003. In the first half of 2004,
inflation will be below the target, given an unchanged monetary stance.
Inflation will move within the upper tolerance limit of the inflation target,
which is currently 4½%, as early as the third quarter of this year.
In
the last Monetary Bulletin, the Central Bank presented estimates that flows in
the foreign exchange market this year would support a further strengthening of
the króna. This was based on the outlook that the current account deficit would
shrink substantially to 33 b.kr., outflows on direct and indirect investments
would contract significantly, and that planned external borrowing appeared to be
more than was needed to finance outflows on account of these factors. This has
been borne out. The exchange rate has appreciated significantly recently. By the
end of April it was almost 6½% higher than at the end of January. Developments
so far this year have confirmed the outlook for a much smaller current account
deficit. The fundamentals for the stronger exchange rate are therefore still in
place.
Recent developments confirm the Central Bank's assessment that
last year's depreciation of the króna was from a long-term perspective more than
the fundamentals warranted. Of course, the slide of the króna was based on
market factors, given the currency outflow caused by the current account deficit
and unfavourable expectations. However, the deficit could and surely would have
narrowed without the króna depreciating as much as it did. It is well known that
exchange rates tend to overshoot their medium term equilibrium level when they
undergo a quick reversal. Thus last November the Bank was of the opinion that
the real exchange rate of the króna would rise in one way or another, having
fallen to 15% below the ten-year average in the last quarter of 2001, and even
lower compared with a longer period. It is important for the inflation outlook
that the rise in real exchange rate in the most recent months has been prompted
by a higher nominal exchange rate rather than more inflation. The exchange rate
at the end of this April was marginally higher than at the end of April last
year. The real exchange rate has gone up by more, however, due to higher
inflation than among trading partner countries. According to current estimates
it will be 5½% higher during the second quarter than a year before. However, it
remains some way below the average for the past ten years.
The time may come
when the Central Bank might opt to take advantage of further currency inflows to
boost its external position. Under the current circumstances, however, the
Bank's priority is to attain its inflation target. A great deal of uncertainty
surrounds where the equilibrium exchange rate of the króna lies at any time. One
of the advantages of inflation targeting is that the monetary authorities do not
need to form an exact view on the equilibrium exchange rate. But it is difficult
to infer that the exchange rate of the króna has already surpassed its
equilibrium rate. In this context it should be borne in mind that the roots of
the shrinking current account deficit lie not only in the falling exchange rate.
The following factors can also be pointed out: First, the decline in domestic
demand caused by high interest rates and greater indebtedness; second,
saturation as a result of the preceding wave of investment and purchases of
consumer durables; and third, export growth in sectors such as fisheries whose
production volume is not particularly sensitive to exchange rate changes.
A
half-yearly analysis of financial stability is published in this issue of
Monetary Bulletin. External macroeconomic balance has improved significantly
with the smaller current account deficit and the fact that the challenge posed
by the exchange rate shock is over. The financial system has not suffered a
substantial negative impact from the adjustment so far. On the contrary, credit
institutions have managed to strengthen their positions. The financial system
turned out to be in a better position than suggested by the outlook last year.
However, it should be borne in mind that the good profitability of many credit
institutions is to a considerable extent the result of temporary factors. Thus
it is important for them to remain on the alert, since they may conceivably
still sustain loan losses in the wake of rapid credit expansion in recent years,
especially in view of high indebtedness and debt service burden among businesses
and households. An economic contraction this year and rising unemployment could
also relay further challenges to the financial system. On the whole, however,
there is even more reason now than last year to expect that the financial system
will be able to manage on its own any difficulties that may lie ahead.
The apparent success achieved in restoring stability and bringing
inflation down to a low level is primarily the result of the tight monetary
stance that has been adhered to in recent times. High interest rates have
reduced investment and private consumption, which in turn has contributed both
to reducing the current account deficit and establishing better balance in the
labour market. The consequence has been that wage drift has halted and
businesses will have to increase productivity and cut costs instead of putting
up prices. Yet again, this goes to prove that inflation is in the final analysis
a monetary phenomenon. The initiative of the partners on the labour market took
place within this framework in the sense that the tight monetary stance
contributed to lower inflation, making it difficult to seek wage rises in order
to compensate for previous price rises. This does not alter the fact that this
initiative was extremely important and undoubtedly promotes faster disinflation,
and probably ultimately less cost in the form of lost economic growth and
unemployment, than would otherwise have been the case.
The Central
Bank has now lowered its policy interest rate twice in a short time, by a total
of 0.8 percentage points. In spite of these reductions, the monetary stance
remains tight when measured in view of inflation expectations and forecast
inflation. In light of the emerging slack, it would be desirable for Central
Bank interest rates to continue to go down in the months to come. The Central
Bank's main objective, however, involves maintaining inflation around a rate of
2½%. The current inflation forecast suggests that conditions will soon be in
place for a further cut in the Bank's policy interest rate. The next step is
linked to the price target this May set by the labour market partners. If all
uncertainty can be dispelled as to whether current wage agreements will remain
in force, the Bank will in all probability cut its interest rates soon
afterwards.
Nr. 6/2002
May 7, 2002